Quasilinear utility
In economics and consumer theory, quasilinear utility functions are linear in one argument, generally the numeraire. Quasilinear preferences can be represented by the utility function where is strictly concave.[1]: 164 A useful property of the quasilinear utility function is that the Marshallian/Walrasian demand for does not depend on wealth and is thus not subject to a wealth effect;[1]: 165–166 The absence of a wealth effect simplifies analysis[1]: 222 and makes quasilinear utility functions a common choice for modelling. Furthermore, when utility is quasilinear, compensating variation (CV), equivalent variation (EV), and consumer surplus are algebraically equivalent.[1]: 163 In mechanism design, quasilinear utility ensures that agents can compensate each other with side payments.
Definition in terms of preferences
[edit]A preference relation is quasilinear with respect to commodity 1 (called, in this case, the numeraire commodity) if:
- All the indifference sets are parallel displacements of each other along the axis of commodity 1. That is, if a bundle "x" is indifferent to a bundle "y" (x~y), then [2]
- Good 1 is desirable; that is,
In other words: a preference relation is quasilinear if there is one commodity, called the numeraire, which shifts the indifference curves outward as consumption of it increases, without changing their slope.
In two dimensional case, the indifference curves are parallel; which is useful because the entire utility function can be determined from a single indifference curve.
Definition in terms of utility functions
[edit]A utility function is quasilinear in commodity 1 if it is in the form
where is an arbitrary function.[3] In the case of two goods this function could be, for example,
The quasilinear form is special in that the demand functions for all but one of the consumption goods depend only on the prices and not on the income. E.g, with two commodities with prices px = 1 and py , if
then, maximizing utility subject to the constraint that the demands for the two goods sum to a given income level, the demand for y is derived from the equation
so
which is independent of the income I.
The indirect utility function in this case is
which is a special case of the Gorman polar form.[1]: 154, 169
Equivalence of definitions
[edit]The cardinal and ordinal definitions are equivalent in the case of a convex consumption set with continuous preferences that are locally non-satiated in the first argument.[citation needed]
See also
[edit]- Quasiconvex function
- Linear utility function - a special type of a quasilinear utility function.
References
[edit]- ^ a b c d e Varian, Hal (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 0-393-95735-7.
- ^ Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael; Green, Jerry (1995). "3". Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. p. 45.
- ^ "Topics in Consumer Theory" (PDF). hks.harvard.edu. August 2006. pp. 87–88. Archived from the original (PDF) on 15 December 2011.