Nonlinear expectation

From Wikipedia the free encyclopedia

In probability theory, a nonlinear expectation is a nonlinear generalization of the expectation. Nonlinear expectations are useful in utility theory as they more closely match human behavior than traditional expectations.[1] The common use of nonlinear expectations is in assessing risks under uncertainty. Generally, nonlinear expectations are categorized into sub-linear and super-linear expectations dependent on the additive properties of the given sets. Much of the study of nonlinear expectation is attributed to work of mathematicians within the past two decades.

Definition[edit]

A functional (where is a vector lattice on a given set ) is a nonlinear expectation if it satisfies:[2][3][4]

  1. Monotonicity: if such that then
  2. Preserving of constants: if then

The complete consideration of the given set, the linear space for the functions given that set, and the nonlinear expectation value is called the nonlinear expectation space.

Often other properties are also desirable, for instance convexity, subadditivity, positive homogeneity, and translative of constants.[2] For a nonlinear expectation to be further classified as a sublinear expectation, the following two conditions must also be met:

  1. Subadditivity: for then
  2. Positive homogeneity: for then

For a nonlinear expectation to instead be classified as a superlinear expectation, the subadditivity condition above is instead replaced by the condition:[5]

  1. Superadditivity: for then

Examples[edit]

  • Choquet expectation: a subadditive or superadditive integral that is used in image processing and behavioral decision theory.
  • g-expectation via nonlinear BSDE's: frequently used to model financial drift uncertainty.[6]
  • If is a risk measure then defines a nonlinear expectation.
  • Markov Chains: for the prediction of events undergoing model uncertainties.[7]

References[edit]

  1. ^ Peng, Shige (2017). "Theory, methods and meaning of nonlinear expectation theory". Scientia Sinica Mathematica. 47 (10): 1223–1254. doi:10.1360/N012016-00209. S2CID 125094517.
  2. ^ a b Peng, Shige (2006). "G–Expectation, G–Brownian Motion and Related Stochastic Calculus of Itô Type". Abel Symposia. 2. Springer-Verlag. arXiv:math/0601035. Bibcode:2006math......1035P.
  3. ^ Peng, Shige (2004). "Nonlinear Expectations, Nonlinear Evaluations and Risk Measures". Stochastic Methods in Finance (PDF). Lecture Notes in Mathematics. Vol. 1856. pp. 165–138. doi:10.1007/978-3-540-44644-6_4. ISBN 978-3-540-22953-7. Archived from the original (PDF) on March 3, 2016. Retrieved August 9, 2012.
  4. ^ Peng, Shige (2019). Nonlinear Expectations and Stochastic Calculus under Uncertainty. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer. doi:10.1007/978-3-662-59903-7. ISBN 978-3-662-59902-0.
  5. ^ Molchanov, Ilya; Mühlemann, Anja (2021-01-01). "Nonlinear expectations of random sets". Finance and Stochastics. 25 (1): 5–41. arXiv:1903.04901. doi:10.1007/s00780-020-00442-3. ISSN 1432-1122. S2CID 254080636.
  6. ^ Chen, Zengjing; Epstein, Larry (2002). "Ambiguity, Risk, and Asset Returns in Continuous Time". Econometrica. 70 (4): 1403–1443. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00337. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 3082003.
  7. ^ Nendel, Max (2021). "Markov chains under nonlinear expectation". Mathematical Finance. 31 (1): 474–507. arXiv:1803.03695. doi:10.1111/mafi.12289. ISSN 1467-9965. S2CID 52064327.